Economic News | CPI cools to 2.8%

  • Thread starter Thread starter nycfan
  • Start date Start date
  • Replies: 1K
  • Views: 34K
  • Politics 
What if Trump is trying to destroy the economy so that Republicans can turn around and drop tax rates to 10% and implement a federal government that resembles one of the 19th century?

The common people will support it because the tax reduction helps dig out of the major recession/depression.

Basically break things and you get to rebuild it the way you want it.

I wouldn’t trust these people to pull that off or to be able to finely manage an economy as would be necessary.

Also Medicare and Social Security would be issues.
 
“Inflation came in cooler for February. That could give Federal Reserve officials extra confidence that price pressures were easing in the U.S. economy, just as President Trump slapped new tariffs on China and threatened higher duties on major trading partners.

The report isn’t likely to change the Fed’s decision to hold rates steady next week. The Fed plays closer attention to a separate gauge that analysts said could show firmer price pressures in February. That reading won't appear until later this month, but a third inflation series due Thursday will tell officials where their preferred measure is likely to stand.
Taken together, this week's two inflation reports could shape economic projections that officials will submit at the meeting. As part of those projections, they will outline their latest expectations for rate cuts this year. …”

 
Oh, I didn't read the units on that chart too well. My vision is getting worse. Need to zoom in more.

1. The relationship between government spending and GDP is complicated. Most economists think that GDP can't be juiced with government spending, because the additional spending crowds out the private sector. The only time GDP can be juiced is when the private sector is operating well below capacity -- as you say, during recessions. That's to say that fiscal spending should be counter-cyclical. Spend money during recessions to boost the economy, and cut spending during a boom because it's not doing much.

2. Keep in mind that Social Security does not affect GDP, along with other social safety net items like unemployment, disability, etc. So a big chunk of that federal spending is not applicable.

1) Is there any evidence that the crowding out effect is occurring? Private sector spending has remained robust. And isn't there a counter argument that if spending is on productive investments (infrastructure, CHIPS) that it has a stimulative effect?

2) This seems to neglect the multiplier affect. If we stop sending out social safety net payments, I can guaranty you GDP is going down.
 
Why does everything have to be extreme?

Before the pandemic, the deficit was less than a trillion dollars. It ballooned during Covid and that made sense but why not just try to target getting back to pre-Covid?

Looking at spending at that time and try to get it back to that. We didn’t have tariffs on Canada and Mexico. Just use that playbook.
 
Why does everything have to be extreme?

Before the pandemic, the deficit was less than a trillion dollars. It ballooned during Covid and that made sense but why not just try to target getting back to pre-Covid?

Looking at spending at that time and try to get it back to that. We didn’t have tariffs on Canada and Mexico. Just use that playbook.
Take back some massive tax cuts also. Right?
 
1) Is there any evidence that the crowding out effect is occurring? Private sector spending has remained robust. And isn't there a counter argument that if spending is on productive investments (infrastructure, CHIPS) that it has a stimulative effect?

2) This seems to neglect the multiplier affect. If we stop sending out social safety net payments, I can guaranty you GDP is going down.
What are you arguing? I was trying to find the first post of yours on this topic and all I saw was "the difference between 20 and 23% is big." It would be helpful to know what you are contending, because otherwise we are speaking in really abstract generalities. But anyway:

1. "Crowding out" isn't really a thing that "occurs." It's a label given to the idea that government spending doesn't boost GDP because GDP growth is hard-capped by the productive capacity of the economy, and mere government spending does little to change that capacity. If we have 10 factories producing at full capacity, and then the government decides to build another battleship -- well, we still have 10 factories producing at full capacity. The objects that would have been sold to consumers is instead sold to the government. So if the private sector spending is robust, that's all the more reason to think that government spending is not juicing the economy on top of that.

Look: economies are complex, and I don't know all the details amidst the weeds. Might a big delta in public spending provide a bit of juice to GDP for a quarter or two? It's possible. Imagine that the government commits to spending $1T more in an economy that is already at full capacity. Well, people can increase their work hours. Maybe some people who work part-time by choice take the opportunity to make some extra money. Maybe firms keep the machines running more of the time. But none of that stuff is sustainable, because they don't change the equilibrium. For instance, if those part-time workers wanted to be full-time workers, they would be. After not too long, they will go back (because if they didn't, we weren't at full capacity). Over a longer term, though, government spending doesn't typically boost GDP unless it increases the productive capacity of the economy more than would the private sector.

2. We need more precise terminology here. "Stimulative" is usually taken to refer the effect of boosting GDP in the short-term. Think about it this way: the economy has a long-run productive capacity. The actual performance of the economy could be 90% of that capacity, as in a recession; it could be 98%, which is a full-capacity story; or 102%, which is an overheating story. When we talk about stimulative effects, we're usually talking about jumping around those figures. In a deep recession, government spending could lift the economy from 90% utilization to 98%. Outside of a recession, it might stimulate if it flickers between 98% and 102%.

When you talk about productive public investment, you're talking about raising the long-term capacity of the economy. That is definitely a good thing! It's not usually considered "stimulative." It's something better, with different words used in different contexts. The interstate highway system didn't stimulate the economy in the 1950s/60s. Well, maybe it did, but that's not why it was important. It increased the total productive capacity of the economy, allowing for more factories to be built, more transport options, etc.

3. The multiplier effect is not a different concept: it's just an arithmetic formulation of the same thing we've been talking about. Let's take a simplifying analogy, and think of the economy as like a huge sporting event. Now, what are the scenarios?

First, the sporting event could be a super bowl. Imagine if the government said, "no seniors can buy tickets" (analogous to cutting off money). It would make not one whit of difference. Demand for super bowl tickets greatly exceeds supply. Maybe, just maybe, you'd see a slight erosion of margins at the scalpers' very highest prices. But for the most part, the story will be the show goes on exactly as before. In this scenario, the multiplier is zero. Whether old people can buy Super Bowl tickets makes no difference at all.

Second, the sporting event could be a UNC football game. Attendance is below capacity, so that means demand is less than supply. Whether seniors can go will affect the production of the football game (economically speaking, the production of an event is value per ticket * tickets sold). But it's not going to meaningfully affect the behavior of the UNC athletic department, which makes capacity decisions on a much longer term basis and has no liquidity crises to deal with. This would be a unity multiplier.

Finally, maybe the sporting event is a minor league baseball game. Here, the attendance of seniors might determine whether the franchise can survive or has to shut down operations. This would be the high-multiplier case. Notice that in each case, the multiplier depends on the state of the economy AND the nature of the stimulus. That's why it's hard to answer these questions across the board.

4. You always have to remember opportunity costs. If you decrease social security payments, that frees up money somewhere else. For instance, it decreases the US deficit, and thus requires investors to buy fewer government bonds, and instead of government bonds they invest in new companies. This is the story told by Republicans from 1980-2016. There's always been some validity to it. The trick is 1) are you getting a dollar for dollar substitution (arguably no) and 2) the wealth distribution effects are highly undesirable.

In the case of social security, there's an additional complication, which is whether the demand has any elasticity to it. For instance, let's suppose all social security money is spent on necessities. Now what happens when you cut social security? Well, someone has to pay the bills. In that case, the cuts to social security will likely fall on children, who now have to spend more money helping their parents make ends meet; or charities, which will raise more money to help the old folks out. Either way, the cessation of payments doesn't actually free up money -- it merely redistributes wealth from the middle upward.

Medicare is different in this regard. If we had no Medicare, health care spending on seniors would dramatically fall. There would be few offsetting adjustments; kids certainly aren't paying the costs that Medicare was picking up. So a cut to Medicare is a direct cut to production. Now, in theory, the economy would rebound -- eventually health care will be cheaper for non-older folks, and perhaps they buy more of it. Maybe deductibles will be reduced. But there would be a big adjustment cost. You'd have a bunch of geriatric specialists who no longer have a job or a practice. Now there has been productive capacity destroyed. Same with nursing homes, geriatric wards at hospitals, the wheelchair industry, etc.

This productive capacity destruction isn't really about levels of spending. It's about exogenous shocks to the economy. Suppose the government said, "we're going to end Medicare in 10 years." The economic impact of that would be considerably less. Few physicians will choose to enter a geriatric field; new nursing homes won't open up; new hospital wings won't be built, etc. Meanwhile, new companies might emerge. Like senior social clubs, where all the seniors who are not going to get life-saving care go to spend their last money and days on hookers and blow. So that type of announced lead time would have fewer effects and arguably a very low multplier.
 
By the way, that's half a semester of macro-economics distilled into one message board post. Please don't nitpick. Asking questions for better understanding is fine. I'm unlikely to engage arguments challenging it, because I've done my best to explain a lot of material in a very short amount of space. Suffice it to say, I've tried to fairly represent mainstream economic positions without regard to ideology. Most of what I wrote would, I believe, find agreement among most economists, without much regard to ideology.

If you don't think this economics is helpful for you (not only the specific poster but a general audience), fine. I would just like some appreciation for the fact that I'm trying to educate. It's a pretty good deal for the consumer; it's free! And while it's not Paul Krugman quality and doesn't come with Krugman's guarantee of getting it right (Krugman being an author of a best selling intro economics textbook), it's free! And available to you.
 
By 0.1% on expectations. That's a margin of error change.
Nearly all monthly reports concern margin-of-error changes. I really wish they would report with greater precision. I mean, anyone can do the math if they want, except message board posters who don't really care enough to spend any time on it. This is why you look at the longer term.

Before this month's 0.2% sequential reading, inflation had been rising at a 6% annual clip since election day. Factoring this in brings that down to maybe 4, 4.5%. I thought we might see 8%, but that was contingent on the tariffs being implemented. Yet to be seen if that's going to happen. Of course, we're already seeing price increases from tariffs, because a) we are still paying tariffs on goods from China and b) retailers and producers will use the opportunity to increase prices, so that the introduction of the tariff won't be such a shock. But obviously, the inflationary effects of quasi-tariffs is going to be less than full tariffs.
 
That is promising. Let us all hope the trend continues.
Is this sarcastic? I want the economy to crash and burn. We have a big election coming up in the Senate in 2026, and Dems need to pick up several seats to have a lever of control over Trump's fuckery. A crashed economy is the best way to make that happen. We have huge pickup opportunities in Maine and NC, which are probably lean-D in an off year election. But we need more. We need to pick off JD Vance's seat, for instance. Maybe Joni Ernst in IA? Those seats are in play in a wrecked economy with high inflation. Probably not in a decent economy.
 
What are you arguing? I was trying to find the first post of yours on this topic and all I saw was "the difference between 20 and 23% is big." It would be helpful to know what you are contending, because otherwise we are speaking in really abstract generalities. But anyway:

1. "Crowding out" isn't really a thing that "occurs." It's a label given to the idea that government spending doesn't boost GDP because GDP growth is hard-capped by the productive capacity of the economy, and mere government spending does little to change that capacity. If we have 10 factories producing at full capacity, and then the government decides to build another battleship -- well, we still have 10 factories producing at full capacity. The objects that would have been sold to consumers is instead sold to the government. So if the private sector spending is robust, that's all the more reason to think that government spending is not juicing the economy on top of that.

Look: economies are complex, and I don't know all the details amidst the weeds. Might a big delta in public spending provide a bit of juice to GDP for a quarter or two? It's possible. Imagine that the government commits to spending $1T more in an economy that is already at full capacity. Well, people can increase their work hours. Maybe some people who work part-time by choice take the opportunity to make some extra money. Maybe firms keep the machines running more of the time. But none of that stuff is sustainable, because they don't change the equilibrium. For instance, if those part-time workers wanted to be full-time workers, they would be. After not too long, they will go back (because if they didn't, we weren't at full capacity). Over a longer term, though, government spending doesn't typically boost GDP unless it increases the productive capacity of the economy more than would the private sector.

2. We need more precise terminology here. "Stimulative" is usually taken to refer the effect of boosting GDP in the short-term. Think about it this way: the economy has a long-run productive capacity. The actual performance of the economy could be 90% of that capacity, as in a recession; it could be 98%, which is a full-capacity story; or 102%, which is an overheating story. When we talk about stimulative effects, we're usually talking about jumping around those figures. In a deep recession, government spending could lift the economy from 90% utilization to 98%. Outside of a recession, it might stimulate if it flickers between 98% and 102%.

When you talk about productive public investment, you're talking about raising the long-term capacity of the economy. That is definitely a good thing! It's not usually considered "stimulative." It's something better, with different words used in different contexts. The interstate highway system didn't stimulate the economy in the 1950s/60s. Well, maybe it did, but that's not why it was important. It increased the total productive capacity of the economy, allowing for more factories to be built, more transport options, etc.

3. The multiplier effect is not a different concept: it's just an arithmetic formulation of the same thing we've been talking about. Let's take a simplifying analogy, and think of the economy as like a huge sporting event. Now, what are the scenarios?

First, the sporting event could be a super bowl. Imagine if the government said, "no seniors can buy tickets" (analogous to cutting off money). It would make not one whit of difference. Demand for super bowl tickets greatly exceeds supply. Maybe, just maybe, you'd see a slight erosion of margins at the scalpers' very highest prices. But for the most part, the story will be the show goes on exactly as before. In this scenario, the multiplier is zero. Whether old people can buy Super Bowl tickets makes no difference at all.

Second, the sporting event could be a UNC football game. Attendance is below capacity, so that means demand is less than supply. Whether seniors can go will affect the production of the football game (economically speaking, the production of an event is value per ticket * tickets sold). But it's not going to meaningfully affect the behavior of the UNC athletic department, which makes capacity decisions on a much longer term basis and has no liquidity crises to deal with. This would be a unity multiplier.

Finally, maybe the sporting event is a minor league baseball game. Here, the attendance of seniors might determine whether the franchise can survive or has to shut down operations. This would be the high-multiplier case. Notice that in each case, the multiplier depends on the state of the economy AND the nature of the stimulus. That's why it's hard to answer these questions across the board.

4. You always have to remember opportunity costs. If you decrease social security payments, that frees up money somewhere else. For instance, it decreases the US deficit, and thus requires investors to buy fewer government bonds, and instead of government bonds they invest in new companies. This is the story told by Republicans from 1980-2016. There's always been some validity to it. The trick is 1) are you getting a dollar for dollar substitution (arguably no) and 2) the wealth distribution effects are highly undesirable.

In the case of social security, there's an additional complication, which is whether the demand has any elasticity to it. For instance, let's suppose all social security money is spent on necessities. Now what happens when you cut social security? Well, someone has to pay the bills. In that case, the cuts to social security will likely fall on children, who now have to spend more money helping their parents make ends meet; or charities, which will raise more money to help the old folks out. Either way, the cessation of payments doesn't actually free up money -- it merely redistributes wealth from the middle upward.

Medicare is different in this regard. If we had no Medicare, health care spending on seniors would dramatically fall. There would be few offsetting adjustments; kids certainly aren't paying the costs that Medicare was picking up. So a cut to Medicare is a direct cut to production. Now, in theory, the economy would rebound -- eventually health care will be cheaper for non-older folks, and perhaps they buy more of it. Maybe deductibles will be reduced. But there would be a big adjustment cost. You'd have a bunch of geriatric specialists who no longer have a job or a practice. Now there has been productive capacity destroyed. Same with nursing homes, geriatric wards at hospitals, the wheelchair industry, etc.

This productive capacity destruction isn't really about levels of spending. It's about exogenous shocks to the economy. Suppose the government said, "we're going to end Medicare in 10 years." The economic impact of that would be considerably less. Few physicians will choose to enter a geriatric field; new nursing homes won't open up; new hospital wings won't be built, etc. Meanwhile, new companies might emerge. Like senior social clubs, where all the seniors who are not going to get life-saving care go to spend their last money and days on hookers and blow. So that type of announced lead time would have fewer effects and arguably a very low multplier.
So there would be a bit of a "detox" period as we adjust to less government spending. That's my only point. I don't find the administration's statement wild. The government spending $900 billion less than they did in the previous year is a big deal.
 
Is this sarcastic? I want the economy to crash and burn. We have a big election coming up in the Senate in 2026, and Dems need to pick up several seats to have a lever of control over Trump's fuckery. A crashed economy is the best way to make that happen. We have huge pickup opportunities in Maine and NC, which are probably lean-D in an off year election. But we need more. We need to pick off JD Vance's seat, for instance. Maybe Joni Ernst in IA? Those seats are in play in a wrecked economy with high inflation. Probably not in a decent economy.
I didn't know you were that kind of an asshole. Geez.
 
Back
Top